¥3,422 税込
ポイント: 34pt  (1%)  詳細はこちら
配送料 ¥257 6月15日-26日にお届け(18 時間 4 分以内にご注文の場合)
詳細を見る
通常4~5日以内に発送します。 在庫状況について
¥3,422 () 選択したオプションを含めます。 最初の月の支払いと選択されたオプションが含まれています。 詳細
価格
小計
¥3,422
小計
初期支払いの内訳
レジで表示される配送料、配送日、注文合計 (税込)。
Kindleアプリのロゴ画像

無料のKindleアプリをダウンロードして、スマートフォン、タブレット、またはコンピューターで今すぐKindle本を読むことができます。Kindleデバイスは必要ありません

ウェブ版Kindleなら、お使いのブラウザですぐにお読みいただけます。

携帯電話のカメラを使用する - 以下のコードをスキャンし、Kindleアプリをダウンロードしてください。

KindleアプリをダウンロードするためのQRコード

著者をフォロー

何か問題が発生しました。後で再度リクエストしてください。

Pedigree: How Elite Students Get Elite Jobs ペーパーバック – 2016/3/22

4.4 5つ星のうち4.4 107個の評価

{"desktop_buybox_group_1":[{"displayPrice":"¥3,422","priceAmount":3422.00,"currencySymbol":"¥","integerValue":"3,422","decimalSeparator":null,"fractionalValue":null,"symbolPosition":"left","hasSpace":false,"showFractionalPartIfEmpty":true,"offerListingId":"OZ1OuTBskbHROQJlh77ZfE1vpRcvIdi7UT%2Btqh3vMAj9GVFOalDMrwv9cTWBt0SDuwSyu9pA%2B1SrLaAr1HaXGyLeCG2mMKr1NaDx1v1yOYAs4GDObJzSFgdhVa%2FMhtn3qp1EOgRmnxvs4M6w1jOEYeW8dzrn2f%2BIN5mr5QDVe%2B1Iv1UKAql5R12XSQ5O3MjD","locale":"ja-JP","buyingOptionType":"NEW","aapiBuyingOptionIndex":0}]}

購入オプションとあわせ買い

商品の説明

レビュー

"Pedigree: How Elite Students Get Elite Jobs is an academic book with the requisite references to gender theory and Marxist concepts of inequality. But read it carefully and it becomes something far more useful--a guide on how to join the global elite."-- "Economist"

"[
Pedigree] provides an insider look at how top-notch places hire, and explores how their processes serve those with the most privileged and affluent backgrounds."---Bouree Lam, The Atlantic

"[Rivera's] richly described account is mesmerising--and horrifying."
---Gillian Tett, Financial Times

"A rich and yet remarkably clear book."
---Bruno Cousin, European Journal of Sociology

"By demonstrating how leaders of firms select upon educational status, traits they already find in their midst, and prefer applicants that mirror their own pasts, trajectories, and skills, Rivera has provided important evidence for mechanisms of the (re)production of inequality. Those interested in the sociology of culture, in labor markets, and in elites and stratification will find Rivera's book necessary reading."
---Shamus Khan, American Journal of Sociology

"Co-Winner of the 2016 Distinguished Book Award, Sociology of Law Section of the American Sociological Association"

"Co-Winner of the 2016 Silver Medal in Career (Job Search, Career Advancement), Axiom Business Book Awards"

"Forget Hollywood. Forget the American Dream. In
Pedigree, Lauren Rivera discloses the harsh reality of landing a job on Wall Street. . . . In this valuable book, [she] sheds light on [the] selection process, homing in on how employers contribute to elite reproduction. The outcome is a highly informed analysis of class and cultural capital."---Angelia Wilson, Times Higher Education

"One of Choice's Outstanding Academic Titles for 2015"

"Winner of the 2016 Mary Douglas Prize for Best Book, Sociology of Culture Section of the American Sociological Association"

"Winner of the 2016 Max Weber Book Award, Organizations, Occupations, and Work Section of the American Sociological Association"

抜粋

Pedigree

How Elite Students get Elite Jobs

By Lauren A. Rivera

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS

Copyright © 2015 Lauren A. Rivera
All rights reserved.
ISBN: 978-0-691-16927-9

Contents

Acknowledgments, xi,
1 Entering the Elite, 1,
2 The Playing Field, 29,
3 The Pitch, 55,
4 The Paper, 83,
5 Setting the Stage for Interviews, 113,
6 Beginning the Interview: Finding a Fit, 135,
7 Continuing the Interview: The Candidate's Story, 147,
8 Concluding the Interview: The Final Acts, 183,
9 Talking It Out: Deliberating Merit, 211,
10 Social Reconstruction, 253,
11 Conclusion, 267,
Afterword to the Paperback Edition, 287,
Appendix A Who Is Elite?, 291,
Appendix B Methodological Details, 295,
Appendix C List of Interviews, 311,
Notes, 319,
References, 351,
Index, 369,


CHAPTER 1

Entering the Elite


Most Americans believe that hard work — not blue blood — is the key to success. Textbooks, newspapers, and novels are filled with Horatio Alger stories in which an individual rises to the top through personal drive and perseverance. Whether these narratives focus on Warren Buffett or Homeless to Harvard, the underlying message is the same: economic and social positions are achieved, not inherited from one's parents. The people at the top are there because of their own intellect, unflagging effort, and strong character. Those at the bottom have their own weaknesses to blame.

Despite this widespread faith in a monetary payoff for hard work and belief in myths of a classless society, economic inequality is now greater in the United States than in many other Western industrialized nations, and American rates of social mobility are lower. Contrary to our national lore, the chances of ascending from meager beginnings to affluence or falling from fortune to poverty are slim. The top and bottom rungs of America's economic ladder are particularly sticky; children born to families in the top or bottom fifths of the income distribution tend to stay on those same rungs as adults. Children from families at the top of the economic hierarchy monopolize access to good schools, prestigious universities, and high-paying jobs.

This raises an obvious but pressing question: In an era of merit-based admissions in education and equal opportunity regulations in employment, how is it that this process of elite reproduction occurs? Social scientists in a variety of disciplines have examined how historical and economic changes at home and abroad, social policies, and technological factors have contributed to the concentration of wealth and income at the top of the economic ladder. These studies inform us about crucial drivers of economic inequality, but they do not tell us enough about how and why economic privilege is passed on so consistently from one generation to the next.

Sociologists interested in social stratification — the processes that sort individuals into positions that provide unequal levels of material and social rewards — historically have focused on studying poverty rather than affluence. Recently, though, cultural sociologists have turned their attention to the persistence of privilege. Focusing on schooling, these scholars have illuminated ways in which affluent and well-educated parents pass along advantages that give their children a competitive edge in the realm of formal education. Missing from this rich literature, however, is an in-depth investigation of how elite reproduction takes place after students graduate, when they enter the workforce. We know that even among graduates from the same universities, students from the most elite backgrounds tend to get the highest-paying jobs. But how and why does this happen?

To answer this question, I turn to the gatekeepers who govern access to elite jobs and high incomes: employers. Ultimately, getting a job and entering a specific income bracket are contingent on judgments made by employers. The hiring decisions employers make play important roles in shaping individuals' economic trajectories and influencing broader social inequalities. In this book, I investigate hiring processes in some of the nation's highest-paying entry-level jobs: positions in top-tier investment banks, management consulting firms, and law firms. My analysis draws on interviews with employees of all three firm types, observation of their recruitment events, and in-depth participant observation of a representative firm's recruiting department. I examine the behind-closed-doors decisions that these employers make as they recruit, evaluate, and select new entry-level employees from the ranks of undergraduate and professional school students; and I show how these decisions help explain why socioeconomically privileged students tend to get the most elite jobs.

I argue that at each stage of the hiring process — from the decision about where to post job advertisements and hold recruitment events to the final selections made by hiring committees — employers use an array of sorting criteria ("screens") and ways of measuring candidates' potential ("evaluative metrics") that are highly correlated with parental income and education. Taken together, these seemingly economically neutral decisions result in a hiring process that filters students based on their parents' socioeconomic status.

The book's title, Pedigree, refers to the term that employers in elite firms used as shorthand for a job candidate's record of accomplishments. "Pedigree" was widely seen as a highly desirable, if not mandatory, applicant trait. Significant personal achievements (such as admission to an elite university, being a varsity athlete at an Ivy League college, or having an early internship at Goldman Sachs) were interpreted as evidence of the applicant's intelligence, orientation to success, and work ethic. Employers considered pedigree a quality based purely on individual effort and ability. Yet the original meaning of the term, still widely in use today, is synonymous not with effort but rather with inheritance-based privilege, literally meaning "ancestral line." In that sense, the title evokes the book's main argument that hiring decisions that appear on the surface to be based only on individual merit are subtly yet powerfully shaped by applicants' socioeconomic backgrounds. In the twenty-first century, parents' levels of income and education help determine who works on Wall Street, who works on Main Street, and who reaches the top of the nation's economic ladder.

In the remainder of this chapter, I discuss foundational scholarship relevant to elite reproduction in hiring, describe the study I conducted, outline my argument, and provide an overview of the subsequent chapters. I begin by reviewing the literature on socioeconomic inequalities in education. This research is relevant not only because schools shape the pipeline of applicants to jobs but also because this scholarship reveals general mechanisms of social stratification.


ELITE REPRODUCTION VIA EDUCATION

Economic inequalities that occur long before job offers are made help explain how elite kids come to have elite jobs. In prior eras, elite reproduction in the United States commonly took the form of parents handing the reins of companies or family fortunes to their adult children. Today, the transmission of economic privilege from one generation to the next tends to be indirect. It operates largely through the educational system.

Higher education has become one of the most important vehicles of social stratification and economic inequality in the United States. The earnings gulf between those who graduate from high school and those who graduate from college has nearly doubled over the past thirty years. Graduates of four-year colleges and universities typically now make 80 percent more than graduates of high school alone.

Despite the rapid expansion of higher education over the past fifty years and the popularity of national narratives of "college for all," children from the nation's most affluent families still monopolize universities. Roughly 80 percent of individuals born into families in the top quartile of household incomes will obtain bachelor's degrees, while only about 10 percent of those from the bottom quartile will do so. The relationship between family income and attendance is even stronger at selective colleges and universities. In fact, holding constant precollege characteristics associated with achievement, parental income is a powerful predictor of admission to the nation's most elite universities. These trends persist into graduate education, where over half of the students at top-tier business and law schools come from families from the top 10 percent of incomes nationally.

Many Americans are content to explain these disparities in terms of individual aspirations or abilities alone. But research shows that affluent and educated parents pass on critical economic, social, and cultural advantages to their children that give their kids a leg up in school success as well as the race for college admissions. Scholars often refer to these three types of advantages as forms of "capital," because each can be cashed in for access to valued symbolic and material rewards, such as prestigious jobs and high salaries.


Economic Advantages

Income, wealth, and other types of economic capital are the most obvious resources that well-off parents can mobilize to procure educational advantages for their children. Simply put, affluent parents have more money to invest in their children's educational growth and indeed do spend more on it. A crucial manner in which economic capital can provide children with educational advantages is through enabling school choice. The United States is one of the few Western industrialized countries where public primary and secondary school funding is based largely on property values within a given region. Consequently, high-quality public schools are disproportionately concentrated in geographic areas where property values are the highest and residents tend to be the most affluent. Families with more money are better able to afford residences in areas that offer high-quality schools and school districts. In fact, for many affluent families with children, school quality is one of the most important factors used to decide where to live. Heightened economic resources can also enable parents to send their children to private schools, regardless of the neighborhood in which they reside. In major metropolitan areas, private school tuition can run close to forty thousand dollars per year per child, beginning in kindergarten.

Together, these patterns make it more likely that children from well-off families will attend primary and secondary schools that have higher per-student spending, better-quality teachers, and more modern and ample learning materials and resources than students from less affluent families. At the secondary school level, children from economically privileged homes are more likely to attend schools with plentiful honors and advanced placement (AP) courses, athletics, art, music, and drama programs; these schools also are likely to have well-staffed college counseling offices. Attending schools with such offerings not only enhances students' cognitive and social development but also helps them build academic and extracurricular profiles that are competitive for college admissions. Compounding these advantages, selective college admissions committees give preference to students from schools with strong reputations for academic excellence. In short, the primary and secondary schools that children attend play significant roles in whether they will go to college, and if so, to which ones. Students in resource-rich, academically strong schools — which are dominated by affluent families — are more likely to attend four-year universities and selective colleges than are children who attend less well-endowed schools and live in lower-income neighborhoods.

Given the high cost of university tuition, parents' economic resources influence what colleges (or graduate schools) students apply to and which they ultimately attend. As sociologist Alexandra Walton Radford shows in a recent study of high school valedictorians, many top-achieving students from lower-income families do not apply to prestigious, private, four-year universities because of the high price tags associated with these schools. Illustrating how money and cultural know-how work together, some who would have qualified for generous financial aid packages from these institutions did not apply because they were unaware of such opportunities. Others had difficulty obtaining the extensive documentation required for financial aid applications. By contrast, students from affluent families in Radford's study made their college choices based on noneconomic factors, such as academic or extracurricular offerings, or feelings of personal "fit" with a university or its student body.

Once on campus, parental financial support can help offset the cost of children's college tuition and living expenses. Freed from the need for paid employment, students from well-off families can concentrate on academic and social activities and accept unpaid internships, all of which can facilitate college success, valuable social connections, and future employment opportunities. Those who have to work part- or full-time to pay tuition bills or to send money to family members do not have this luxury. To summarize, parents with more economic capital can more easily help their children receive better-quality schooling, cultivate the types of academic and extracurricular profiles desired by selective college admissions offices, and participate fully in the life of the college they attend.


Social Connections

Money is only part of the story, however. Social capital — the size, status, and reach of people's social networks — is important, too. Parents' social connections can provide their children with access to vital opportunities, information, and resources. For example, parents in the same social network can share information about the best teachers in a school or pass along tips for getting on a principal's or coach's good side. Likewise, a well-placed contact can nudge a private school, college, or internship application toward acceptance. Students' social networks also matter. Having college-oriented friends and peers can shape aspirations, motivate performance, and supply insider tips on how to navigate the college admissions process.


Cultural Resources

Finally, cultural resources — the frames of knowledge, perception, interpretation, and behavior we use to navigate the social world — are important drivers of elite reproduction. These types of resources frequently go unrecognized as mechanisms of inequality because they often are invisible, and people may conflate them with measures of individual ability. Yet cultural resources are powerful drivers of stratification, especially when it comes to gaining access to society's upper echelons. Culture contributes to the persistence of privilege (and underprivilege) through shaping people's aspirations and worldviews, how people judge and are judged by others in everyday social interactions, and their success in navigating society's gatekeeping institutions.


Aspirations and Worldviews

Our economic rank in society shapes how we see the world and our place in it. French sociologist Pierre Bourdieu — whose ideas have had a profound impact on scholarly understandings of how privilege is passed from one generation to the next — argued that beginning in childhood, individuals learn class-specific tastes, values, interaction styles (e.g., etiquette and conversational styles), modes of self-presentation (e.g., dress, speech, and body language), and behaviors. The amount of material resources in children's immediate environments can shape the types of activities, opportunities, and behaviors they encounter as well as those that they find desirable. Due to real material constraints in their immediate environment and concerns about meeting everyday survival needs, individuals from lower classes often come to prefer objects, opportunities, and experiences that have practical, immediate value. By contrast, members of privileged classes, who are free of subsistence concerns, gravitate toward goods and practices that are less directly useful; more ephemeral, abstract, complex, and difficult to acquire; and require significant investments of time, money, and energy. Such class-based differences manifest in a variety of domains, ranging from the types of music that people enjoy to the sports they play. When it comes to sports, for example, individuals from less affluent backgrounds may gravitate toward games that have low economic barriers to entry and straightforward rules, such as pickup basketball or soccer, whereas more affluent individuals are more likely to play sports that require extensive training and expensive equipment or uniforms, can only be played in specific, elite spaces, or have elaborate rules, such as court tennis, squash, or polo.

Most directly relevant for economic inequality, these patterns shape individuals' ideas about what types of educational and career opportunities are desirable, or even possible. For instance, individuals from less affluent backgrounds tend to emphasize pay and stability in job choice; those from more affluent backgrounds tend to place greater stress on the abstract values of on-the-job fulfillment, enjoyment, and self-expression in career choice. These economically grounded distinctions in ways of seeing and being in the world contribute to social reproduction by steering individuals toward social, educational, and occupational paths consistent with the economic class in which they grew up.


(Continues...)Excerpted from Pedigree by Lauren A. Rivera. Copyright © 2015 Lauren A. Rivera. Excerpted by permission of PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

登録情報

  • 出版社 ‏ : ‎ Princeton Univ Pr; Reprint版 (2016/3/22)
  • 発売日 ‏ : ‎ 2016/3/22
  • 言語 ‏ : ‎ 英語
  • ペーパーバック ‏ : ‎ 379ページ
  • ISBN-10 ‏ : ‎ 0691169276
  • ISBN-13 ‏ : ‎ 978-0691169279
  • 寸法 ‏ : ‎ 13.97 x 2.54 x 21.59 cm
  • カスタマーレビュー:
    4.4 5つ星のうち4.4 107個の評価

著者について

著者をフォローして、新作のアップデートや改善されたおすすめを入手してください。
Lauren A. Rivera
Brief content visible, double tap to read full content.
Full content visible, double tap to read brief content.

著者の本をもっと発見したり、よく似た著者を見つけたり、著者のブログを読んだりしましょう

カスタマーレビュー

星5つ中4.4つ
5つのうち4.4つ
107グローバルレーティング

この商品をレビュー

他のお客様にも意見を伝えましょう

上位レビュー、対象国: 日本

日本からの0件のレビューとお客様による0件の評価があります

他の国からのトップレビュー

すべてのレビューを日本語に翻訳
Léonard Collon
5つ星のうち5.0 Un excellent ouvrage
2016年12月18日にフランスでレビュー済み
Amazonで購入
Kimberly A. Verska
5つ星のうち5.0 Sheds new light on the gatekeepers of the 1%
2015年7月12日にアメリカ合衆国でレビュー済み
Amazonで購入
21人のお客様がこれが役に立ったと考えています
レポート
ron
5つ星のうち4.0 Why Gaps are slow and/or difficult to close
2017年12月7日にカナダでレビュー済み
Amazonで購入
Amazon Customer
5つ星のうち5.0 Very insightful and well written
2016年11月25日に英国でレビュー済み
Amazonで購入
1人のお客様がこれが役に立ったと考えています
レポート
booktalk29
5つ星のうち4.0 Nothing new, but an interesting read!
2015年6月14日にアメリカ合衆国でレビュー済み
Amazonで購入
28人のお客様がこれが役に立ったと考えています
レポート